Following
a spree of national elections across Europe it is clear that a reformist
majority is emerging across the Continent. In the aftermath of the big
financial crisis and in response to the rise of populist isolationism across
the Channel or across the Atlantic, one thing is clear: necessary and overdue reform
is coming again in Europe. The direction and nature of such reform (whether
bold, decentralising, intergovernmental, pro-federal or their opposites) will
determine the future of Europe and the long-term viability of its institutions.
A key lesson
learned from the financial crisis, which such reform will need to address, is the
necessity for effective fiscal policy coordination in order to safeguard the
viability of the single currency. Excessively diverging economies cannot
coexist well under the straitjacket of the euro.
The
abandonment in practice of the infamous “no-bail-out” clause, that was meant to
impose the required self-discipline and make the euro viable, has raised the
spectre of “moral hazard”. This now forces Europe to adopt alternative credible
controls to ensure that habitual profligacy across some Member States is not rendered
chronic or endemic across the whole Union. Consequently, the independence of
the central bank alone can no longer suffice as guarantor of numismatic
stability. Chaotic fiscal divergence resulting from lack of self-discipline or
sufficient coordination (the price of independence) is bound, experience shows,
to make any monetary policy, when applied simultaneously and indiscriminately on
the “prudent” and the “profligate”, feel like a straitjacket for those that
suffer it (at least half the time) or look completely schizophrenic to a
bystander all the time.
Fiscal coordination, therefore, as a remedy to such “numismatic
schizophrenia”, needs to be the focus of reform. Appropriate mechanisms for such
coordination can take different shapes and forms:
- One option could be the unlimited sharing of liabilities in the form of a Eurobond (i.e. the opposite of “no-bail-out”). We can call this the “Blind” option, as it involves the assumption of blind liabilities by Member States with minimum or no safeguards designed to protect the “prudent” against advantage takers. It would mean that the “profligate” can partake in European affluence at the expense of the “prudent” without having to home-grow the wealth that makes this possible. It would split Europe in resentful creators of wealth and ungrateful consumers of the same.
- Another option could be the forced coordination via the imposition of common fiscal policies on each Member State by a central directorate in Brussels without any sharing of liabilities and without subsidies from the rich to the poor (i.e. without centralising taxation, or spending but merely centralising decision making on these issues). We can call this the “Authoritarian” option because it involves the stronger and more powerful Member States (led by Germany) dictating policy on everybody else.
- A third option could involve the bold transformation of the EU into a genuine Federal State with full (unlimited) sovereignty and parallel formal dissolution of the sovereignty of the Member States. This would include unlimited centralised taxation powers and a federal government managing all fiscal policy centrally. We can call this the “Full Federal” option.
These are
the more obvious options. Each can deliver fiscal coordination and each can be
an effective therapy for monetary schizophrenia. But each has obvious and
severe disadvantages. The Blind and the Full Federal choices would be decried
for opening the floodgates of a dreaded “transfer union”. The Blind choice
would not act as a deterrent but rather as a fertiliser for profligacy and
would cause resentment by the rich. The Authoritarian choice will in turn cause
resentment by the poor. It would make the EU appear abhorrent and would eliminate
national sovereignty in essence but not in form. Brussels would become the synonym of hated dictatorship.
Especially as the EU institutions would be no more than proxy power levers in the
hands of dominant national governments. Rather than solve institutional
imbalances, it would fuel nationalistic antagonisms with unforeseen (although
not unforeseeable) consequence. The Full Federal choice is a noble dream ahead
of its time. The peoples of Europe are just not ready for it. There is too much
euro-scepticism and too many will perceive this as a red flag, a call to arms
to fight the “power-grabbing” EU in order to protect the sacred nation-state
from such existential threat.
But if these
are evidently the wrong choices for Europe, is there no workable alternative, one
that would be “just right”? Europe’s “Goldilocks”
choice would need to avoid not just the “moral hazard” or the “monetary
schizophrenia”, but also the resentment by either rich (or prudent) “givers” or
by poor (or profligate) “underlings”. To this end, it is necessary to implement
a set of fiscal and investment policies that will bring about in the long term real
economic convergence of outcomes,
rather than mere fiscal policy coordination. Effective policies should aim to enable
the poor to catch up, improve economic output and develop an institutional
habit for prudence in economic husbandry, whilst be reassuring to the rich that
they will neither be called to assume unlimited liabilities nor relinquish effective
control of any funds transferred to this end. We need structures that work well
for everybody and that will not just remedy the symptoms but eliminate the
causes of instability. A lofty yet not unattainable aspiration.
Member
States need to be convinced to make way for new supra-national institutions
that can deliver this convergence of outcomes in a balanced manner. Europe
needs a modicum of genuine but limited Federal governance; with defined and
limited taxation and spending powers; with, for instance, a constitutional
limited power to raise federal taxation up to 10% of European GDP by imposing federal
tax rates not exceeding 10% in any category. Member States can continue to
manage incremental taxation (in excess of these limits) in the normal way and
can remain sovereign in the classic (unlimited) sense. This “Goldilocks” option
therefore would involve two distinct layers of governance: a bottom relatively slim
layer of federal governance with a joint budget managed democratically by all
the peoples of Europe in unison and then a thicker layer of Member State
governance on top, with separate local budgets, managed in the traditional way
by each Member State, without hindrance or central control from the Federal
State, subject only to the principles of the stability pact and provisions
regarding the ESM. The ratio (of relative size) between these two layers could
be between 1:5 to 1:4 in favour of Member States, over the Federal State: for
every Euro managed centrally and jointly by the Federal State would amount a
further four to five Euros managed by the Member States.
Convergence
would come about in three ways: first, a material portion of the overall
European economy (the bottom layer mentioned above) would be managed centrally
ensuring uniformity of method and outcomes across the Union; second, the Federal
State would dedicate funds with the constitutionally binding strategic aim of
actively pursuing such convergence; and third, the Member States would in
addition engage in closer coordination amongst themselves with the mediation of
(but not commandeering from) the Federal State and there would be mutual
oversight of their respective budgets and finances, although without going as
far as dictating tax rates or fiscal policy, in respect of which Member States
should continue to be free and independent actors.
This
Goldilocks option would require the reconstitution of the EU parliament as a
normal semi-sovereign parliament, with direct yet limited and constitutionally
defined taxation powers and with the prerogative to elect and control a federal
government. Such parliament would have only so many powers as are conferred upon
it in a limited way by a new treaty.
Given
that current EU budget is only about 1% of EU GDP, the new Federal State would
be considerably more powerful, under this approach, with the competence to
raise (and redistribute) as much as 10% of EU GDP in taxation, ten times the
current budget. At the same time the powers of the national Member States would
not be eroded radically. They would still be in charge of the lion’s share of
the economy, with unlimited taxation powers, on top of the limited federal
taxes. In current figures, where overall taxation in Member States is about
45-50% of GDP, this means that if the bottom 10% were to shift to the federal
coffers, the Member States would continue to manage about 35% to 40% of GDP,
i.e. about four times as much as the Federal State, and in any event a very
considerable part of the economy.
Putting even
such a modest, yet material, portion of their resources into a joint pot would empower
the Member States to enable and equip the EU with the competence to pursue the
critical objective of fiscal and broader economic convergence much more
effectively. Rather than blindly share all liabilities, rather than allow
strong states autocratically to dictate policy centrally to weaker ones on the
manner in which the totality of the European resources are managed but without
sharing any of these resources, and rather than place the totality of such
resources in the hands of a central super state, the prudent approach surely would
be to place a modest, yet meaningful portion of these resources under joint
democratic control, decided by the people of Europe directly, and not by the
national governments, so as to empower democratic process and defuse
nationalistic antagonisms. This approach would also allow Europe to moderate
the disproportionate power of Germany or other large Member States, something
that Germany itself would find very beneficial.
The
thicker upper layer managed by Member States, in this Goldilocks scenario (of about
35% - 40% of EU GDP) would ensure there is no material diminution of the
nation-state. The nation-state would still be at least 3-4 times more powerful (in
fiscal terms) than the Federal State. Crucially, under this “Goldilocks”
proposal, the nation-state would be free and fully sovereign to manage its own
taxation policies and to set its own tax rates in competition with other Member
States, without hindrance from any central bureaucracy, subject only to a sensible
coordination within the parameters of the stability pact and the rules of ESM.
But any inter-state competition would start on top of the federal rates, which
would provide the “common starting ground”. So, if for example federal
corporate or personal income tax is 10%, no Member State would be able to go
below that and undercut the others, but would need to impose a layer of local
tax on top of the federal tax. Whilst this would not entirely eliminate
competition in the form of aggressively low taxation policies, it would at
least provide a common minimum, “floor”, that would render such practices a
little less aggressive, without going as far as imposing complete uniformity
through some form of fiscal leveller with centrally dictated tax rates (as in
the Authoritarian approach) that would result in diminished inter-state
competition that could ultimately damage the European economy and reduce its
vitality.
The
nation-state is not yet dead or defunct, even if nineteenth-century style nationalism
should be superseded by a more modern and less tribal outlook. The Member
States have a crucial non-nationalist role to play in managing local economies
and participating in European institutional, social and economic progress as
vibrant competitive organisations. This role deserves to be safeguarded, even
if modestly checked, by any future reform.
But what
miracles could the EU deliver if only it had these vital resources, even as
little as 10% of EU GDP! It could provide the basic building block, the bottom
layer of what is required in a number of fields that could begin to make a
difference in achieving social and transnational cohesion (a necessary
prerequisite of growth and prosperity) via effective but controlled redistribution,
either vertically (across social classes) or horizontally (across regions). The
latter (the cross-regional redistribution) would indeed amount to a limited form
of “transfer union”, but a very sensible one, without unlimited liabilities,
and with full and effective democratic controls on the proper management of any
funds so dedicated.
A
transformed EU with enhanced taxation powers (of up to 10% of EU GDP) would be
empowered to provide things such as: (i) badly needed infrastructure investment
in deprived regions, and venture capital across all regions to make the EU the
most open, coherent and entrepreneurial place in the world; (ii) a basic
pan-European minimum income for all and other limited basic universal benefits
making up the first building block to (a minimum federal layer of) a welfare
state entitlement, to make the EU the fairest and happiest place in the world
and partly eliminate the causes of “benefits tourism”; (iii) world-leading
research and development investment to transform the economy to make the EU the
most progressive and forward-looking place in the world; (iv) common security,
defence, immigration and foreign policies to make the EU the safest and most
confident place in the world with maximum control and influence in the near
abroad so as to harness refugee and migratory currents, without illusions
pertaining to “fortress Europe”.
More
importantly, with this Goldilocks option, a meaningful federal budget under
joint trans-national parliamentary (rather than inter-governmental) control,
would force the establishment of a genuine European polis; it would herald true
European democracy and would finally give credence to the notion of EU
citizenship and (limited) shared sovereignty - all the key hitherto missing
ingredients, whose absence has allowed often unfair, but not altogether
unfounded, criticisms about the so-called “democratic deficit” in Europe.
Europeans voting in European elections would (as they do today in their home
countries) elect a parliament with real (if limited) powers over taxation,
which would in turn (in true parliamentary tradition) appoint and control a
European Executive. Europeans would be empowered to directly choose their federal
leaders, as they choose their local ones, for the things that matter in their
daily lives, without intermediaries behind closed doors in the council of
ministers, but in open process in the ballot box on EU-wide party politics. A
senate could replace the council of ministers as the secondary legislative body
representing Member States in the Union. This civic invigoration would be the
greatest and most lasting, perhaps the ultimate unifying transformation that
our generation can yet deliver to the historic peoples of Europe.
This is
our chance, in the coming years to write the next chapter and to attain and bequeath
to our children the dream of many past generations - the vision of a truly
united European People - in the singular; founded in law, shaped by a colourful
diverse but converging history and inspired by our common future: a singular
dream for Europe.
No comments:
Post a Comment